February 25, 2007

The alternative to FC is unprintable - Ahmadinejad and capital markets

Sometimes someone writes a sweeping article that just happens to include why Financial Cryptography is so important, and also so misunderstood. Here's an article by Reuven Brenner (posted by RAH):

What happens when societies either do not have or destroy their financial markets? Even today very few societies have developed the institutions that can enable the development of deep financial markets - a solid legal infrastructure and free media among them. In this scenario, most people wanting access to capital have no other option but to turn to government, which will raise the money - either through taxes or borrowing - and then distribute it.

FC at its core is about all forms value. That means markets, and the forms of markets that FC just happen to excel in are capital markets.

The alternative to access to capital (in other words, FC) is unprintable, at least on this forum, as we are sensitive to the reader's desires for a cosy Sunday and our own desire to believe we are doing the right thing.

Frederich Hayek called it the Fatal Conceit, and Muhammad Yunus showed how it caused poverty. Maggie Thatcher didn't hand it over to Brussels, and more recently, Hernando de Soto said that the Mystery of Capitalism was why they don't have it and we do.

Wherever you stand on mad mullahs, the rise of totalitarianism, wars over trade or gun-ship diplomacy, we would all be well served by liquid markets for capital in emerging markets. This seems to trump everything, or have I missed something?


The National Review

December 19, 2006, 8:42 a.m.

The Economics of the Rise of Ahmadinejad

Capital markets (or their absence) are central to the emergence of evil and the one-party state.

By Reuven Brenner

When Iranian President Mahmoud Ahmadinejad visited the U.S. recently, he didn’t say explicitly that the Holocaust was a myth. Instead he asked why so much emphasis is put on the 6 million Jews who died during WWII rather than the 60 million people who perished during the conflict. Then, at a Tehran conference where Holocaust deniers congregated with Orthodox rabbis who apparently believe the state of Israel should not exist, Ahmadinejad offered a message satisfying each camp. He told the delegates that the Holocaust should be questioned and that Israel’s days are numbered.

One wonders, with the terrible lessons of 20th century totalitarianism still so ripe, how history could repeat itself so blatantly and so soon. I hold that the answer lies in just how one-party states such as modern Iran emerge, and of what happens when the access to capital is limited within societies.

Of course, the systematic extermination of the Jews started in the early 1930s. By then, Germany had rebuilt itself from the ruins of WWI and the devastating hyperinflation of the 1920s into a powerful, educated, industrialized nation, where science and technology thrived. True, all this occurred within a one-party state. Yet, if such apparent prosperity can lead to murderous instincts not being suppressed, where is the advantage of Western Civilization, which is built on the concept of prosperity? In a recent op-ed in the Wall Street Journal, Mark Bowen asked, Why is the Holocaust haunting the collective memory of the West? Bowen concluded, “what the Holocaust demonstrates is the danger of a one-party state.”

This conclusion is partially correct, but it begs the question: How did Germany get from the Weimar Republic, a democracy, to the one-party state? And why did the Germans tolerate such a state and accept its murderous ideology? Whether the Germans agreed deep down with Hitler & Co. is irrelevant. Actions — or, in this case, the lack of actions — matter.

During the 1920s, Germany, Austria, Hungary, Poland, and Russia each printed money with abandon. This brought about hyperinflation, which weakened or destroyed the capital markets in these countries. Banks failed, markets crashed, unemployment rose, and the middle classes lost their lifetime savings.

People want to live first and philosophize a bit later. With their savings gone, these Europeans turned to two other ways of accessing capital: government and crime. Predictably, each of these countries moved toward centralization — that is, government become the main financial intermediary.

When the citizens of these countries looked abroad, there was little to admire. England and the U.S. were each suffering through depressions (in the U.S., due to mistaken fiscal and monetary policies). These governments too moved toward centralization, though to a much different degree. Up sprung the jargon of “public works” and, eventually, the Keynesian term “aggregate demand.” Here the governments also would become intermediaries, charged with raising and then allocating capital. Importantly, however, this was done without England or the U.S. ever becoming one-party states.

Power is dispersed within democracies, and democracies are always weakened when more money flows through government hands. This is true even when the facade of democracy persists. When more capital sifts through the government, more groups depend on government handouts and have less access to sources of capital that are independent from the ruling political parties. But the U.K. and the U.S. retained many more independent sources of capital than did Germany, Austria, Hungary, or Russia during the 1930s.

The dangers come when a country either does not develop its capital markets or destroys them on purpose or inadvertently. When this is the case, the chances of one party taking power and imposing its ideology increase.

Conversely, when capital markets are opened, the risk that one-party states will emerge diminishes. As independent sources of capital surface, political power is dispersed and lasting prosperity follows. Thus, it is a mistake to promote democracy without first establishing the ground for letting people have access to capital and collateral — or at least coordinating such access with political change. After all, prosperity is the result of matching people with capital, while holding both sides accountable.

What happens when societies either do not have or destroy their financial markets? Even today very few societies have developed the institutions that can enable the development of deep financial markets — a solid legal infrastructure and free media among them. In this scenario, most people wanting access to capital have no other option but to turn to government, which will raise the money — either through taxes or borrowing — and then distribute it.

That’s how one-party states such as Ahmadinejad’s Iran emerge: People bet on crazy ideologies when their customary ways of living suddenly crumble and capital markets close. Capital markets are the unique feature of the West, and their democratization is the key to the civilizing process and the best insurance against the emergence of one-party states. Indeed, that’s what the U.S. should have been “exporting” all along in the Middle East, coordinating the promotion of capital markets with the necessary political changes in Iraq.

— Reuven Brenner holds the Repap chair at Desautels’ Faculty of Management, and is partner in Match Strategic Partners. The article draws on his books Force of Finance (2002) and History: The Human Gamble (1983).

Posted by iang at February 25, 2007 12:25 PM | TrackBack
Comments

"People want to live first and philosophize a bit later."

That seems to be the case for most which would mean that most have it backwards now a days.

"... do not have or destroy their financial markets ... most people wanting access to capital have no other option but to turn to government, which will raise the money - either through taxes or borrowing"

First of all, capital is not money or "money" (that [currencies, tokens] which people have been led to believe are as good as money). It is the means of production: heavy machinery, hand tools, computers, code, certain humans and so forth. It's curious that he said "through taxes". If gotten through taxation, that means that it already existed, was already created. It wasn't "raised" by government. Government may have been preventing it from being used to create more value/wealth, however.

"... Western Civilization, which is built on the concept of prosperity ..."

Originally, way way back, back in the renaissance days, I believe, it was built on Aristotelian logic, the maximum use of requires maximum freedom. Considering where the heads of people in Western Civilization, the Anglo Saxon world, the English speaking world, are, we're heading back into a dark age. Good luck.

"Power is dispersed within democracies, and democracies are always weakened when more money flows through government hands."

Currently it seems that there are no democracies in the world, so not sure why he is talking about them. Anyways, a weak democracy would be one where little "money" flows through a government's hands. A strong one, the opposite. Strong enough so that it ends up having a violent death, strong enough to destroy an economy.

Same goes for good (there are some really bad ones) constitutional republics that more and more ignore their constitution (the law of the land) and evolve more and more into, in effect, a democracy.

"Conversely, when capital markets are opened, ..."

Another misuse of the word capital. Stored value in the form of a money, currency or token gets traded on financial markets.

"As independent sources of capital surface, political power is dispersed"

Political power has to be dispersed first before independent sources of stored value surface.

"Capital markets are the unique feature of the West, and their democratization is the key to the civilizing process..."

More freedom is the key, not democracy (the opposite).

"Democracy is four wolves and a sheep voting on what's for dinner."
"Democracy: The crude leading the crud."
"Democracy - the worship of jackals by jackasses."

Something's got to be wrong when statists from republics are busy pushing democracy on every Tom, Dick and Harry in the world rather than their own form of government, a republic.

I don't know. This guy could be a statist in free market drag.

One thing is for sure, more or stronger democracy is the opposite of what is required for better/larger/freer/more dependable/less fraudulent/cheaper/faster markets for financial instruments.

Posted by: bob at February 26, 2007 04:42 AM
Post a comment









Remember personal info?






Hit preview to see your comment as it would be displayed.